Skip to content
CRR logo
Submit Search
Join E-mail List | Contact Us
  • Topics
  • Publications
  • Initiatives
  • Data
  • Sponsors
  • Opportunities
  • About Us
  • Search

Fixing Social Security: Let’s Use Subsidies for Retirement Plans

January 23, 2024
Share
Mobile Share Email Facebook Bluesky Twitter LinkedIn

MarketWatch Blog by Alicia H. Munnell

Headshot of Alicia H. Munnell

Alicia H. Munnell is a columnist for MarketWatch and senior advisor of the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College.

If Andrew Biggs and I can agree, the shift should have bipartisan support.

Andrew Biggs, a conservative economist with the American Enterprise Institute, and I are usually opponents.  Our disagreements go back decades – privatizing Social Security, adequacy of retirement income, compensation of state and local government employees – and just a few weeks ago I thought he was really off base arguing that workers do not pay for their Social Security benefits. 

Sometimes, however, we see things the same way.  We both have concluded that: 1) the subsidies for private sector retirement plans do little to increase private saving; and 2) the revenues raised from repealing these “tax expenditures” could be better used to address Social Security’s funding gap.   The tax expenditures, under the personal income tax, arise because employees can defer taxes on compensation that they receive in the form of retirement savings.  This tax treatment significantly reduces the lifetime taxes of participating employees, relative to saving through an ordinary investment account.  It also cost the government $185 billion in 2020, equal to about 0.9 percent of GDP.

Table showing the present value of tax expenditures for retirement plans, 2020

Who gets the tax expenditure?  Studies show that 59 percent of the current tax expenditures for retirement saving flows to the top quintile of the income distribution.  This pattern is not surprising, given that upper-income taxpayers are more likely to have access to employer-sponsored retirement plans, are more likely to participate in their employer’s plan, and contribute more when they do participate. 

And recent changes will increase the share going to the top quintile.  Expanded “catch-up” contributions benefit only those constrained by the existing limits – roughly 16 percent of participants.  And increasing the age to 75 for taking required minimum distributions allows participants to take advantage of 4½ more years of tax-free growth.  Generally, only the wealthiest will be able to benefit from this provision.

What do the tax expenditures buy us?  Given that the tax expenditures go overwhelmingly to upper-income households, who face almost no risk of poverty in old age, it is important to ask whether these expenditures accomplish some broader social goal, such as increasing national saving. 

Theory does not provide a strong basis for assuming that the federal tax preferences increase total saving.  Yes, tax preferences make retirement saving more attractive and massive amounts have been accumulated in retirement plans.  But the economists’ lifecycle model suggests that people may simply shift savings from ordinary taxable investment accounts to tax-favored retirement accounts.   

Indeed, the evidence supports the predictions of the lifecycle model.  The definitive 2014 study, using Danish tax data, looked at responses to a reduction in the subsidy for retirement contributions for those in the top tax bracket.  The results show that, for some, pension contributions declined.  But the decline was nearly entirely offset by an increase in other types of saving.  The tax subsidy, in other words, had primarily induced individuals to shift their saving from taxable to tax-advantaged retirement accounts, not to increase overall household saving. 

Given that the tax expenditure for retirement plans is a bad deal for taxpayers, it makes sense to curtail these tax breaks and reallocate the proceeds.  Over the next 75 years, Social Security faces an actuarial deficit of 1.3 percent of GDP, so applying the revenues from eliminating the tax expenditure would solve 70 percent of the problem.  And the gains would be higher than this  estimate for two reasons: 1) the government would continue to collect income taxes on past tax-preferred contributions; and 2) payroll tax revenues would be higher as well because they are also affected by the tax preferences. 

In short, let’s move government resources from retirement plans where the incentive does virtually nothing for retirement security to a program that indisputably does – Social Security.

icons of taxes, money, and percent signs with a businessman
icons of taxes, money, and percent signs with a businessman
Downloads
PDF Version
Related Content

Read on MarketWatch

Topics
Social Security
Financing Retirement
Publication Type
MarketWatch Blog
Related Articles
One big pink piggy bank on the left of a seesaw and four smaller money boxes on the other side

The Case for Using Subsidies for Retirement Plans to Fix Social Security

Issue Brief by Andrew G. Biggs and Alicia H. Munnell

January 16, 2024
Hand with magnifying glass focused on coins fly away

The Case for Using Subsidies for Retirement Plans to Fix Social Security

Working Paper by Andrew G. Biggs, Alicia H. Munnell, and Michael Wicklein

January 16, 2024
Scissors and money icons on wooden cubes

President Trump Should Combine Extending Tax Cuts with Fixing Social Security

MarketWatch Blog by Alicia H. Munnell

February 21, 2025

Support timely research that informs real-world solutions.

About us
Contact
Join e-mail list
Facebook Bluesky Twitter LinkedIn Instagram YouTube RSS

© 2025 Trustees of Boston College, Center for Retirement Research|Terms of Use|Privacy Policy|Accessibility

This website uses cookies to improve your experience. We also use IP addresses, domain information and other access statistics to administer the site and analyze usage trends. If you prefer to opt out, you can select Update settings. Read our Privacy Policy. Accept
Privacy & Cookies Policy

Privacy Overview

This website uses cookies to improve your experience while you navigate through the website. Out of these cookies, the cookies that are categorized as necessary are stored on your browser as they are essential for the working of basic functionalities of the website. We also use third-party cookies that help us analyze and understand how you use this website. These cookies will be stored in your browser only with your consent. You also have the option to opt-out of these cookies. But opting out of some of these cookies may have an effect on your browsing experience.
Necessary
Always Enabled
Necessary cookies are absolutely essential for the website to function properly. This category only includes cookies that ensures basic functionalities and security features of the website. These cookies do not store any personal information.
Non-necessary
Any cookies that may not be particularly necessary for the website to function and is used specifically to collect user personal data via analytics, ads, other embedded contents are termed as non-necessary cookies. It is mandatory to procure user consent prior to running these cookies on your website.
SAVE & ACCEPT